Hacker News new | past | comments | ask | show | jobs | submit login
A battle over solar power in Nevada (bloomberg.com)
144 points by elorant on Feb 8, 2016 | hide | past | favorite | 98 comments



The problem here stems from two things:

1) Net metering means that the power company is required to buy electricity at retail rates from their customers instead of wholesale rates, which puts quite a burden on them. Why should they have to buy at a higher rate?

2) Electric companies for decades have been rolling the cost of transmission into the variable rate portion of people's bills. This means that larger consumers (who tend to be richer) have been subsidizing the poorer customers. This is generally considered a good thing by most, since it allows poorer people to have electricity (because you don't want to live in a society where some people have electricity and some don't). The solution here is to raise the fixed portion of the bill to cover the true cost of transmission, and then place a tax on those who go "off grid" to straight out subsidize the poor, so it's more obvious that is what is happening (And presumably most people would still support).


One reason net-metering is close to fair is that we are talking about delivered electricity. Every unit I send back to the grid is a unit that doesn't need to be delivered by the power company but the power company can sell it to my neighbor for retail price.

A second reason net-metering is close to fair is because mid-day units of electricity are more valuable. Solar production peaks midday while household usage is U-shaped, so most production flows out to the grid during the high-price periods. Rates average peak and off-peak pricing so rate customers typically don't see that.

In other words, solar production produces high-value kWhs the utility can sell to my neighbor for retail, even though they don't have to generate or deliver it themselves.


Hey, as someone who used to work for an energy utility looking at setting up a solar market place, there's some info you're missing:

- The wholesale price is the cost of generating electricity. The retail price includes the cost of serving the customer, i.e. billing. Sure, there are less transmission costs, but in New Zealand they only play about 20% of the retail cost.

- Also, just because midday rates of electricity are high, those high rates tend to subsidise the cost of running the network when rates are low (i.e. other times). Power Stations don't come for free. People want security of supply, but then to be able to poach from the most profitable parts of the day?


I don't know why your first point is relevant, the marginal cost of billing is incredibly minute. The second point is interesting but calling it poaching is tendentious. No one is saying power stations, transmission lines, distribution networks, voltage support, frequency regulation, or any of the other myriad features of modern electricity grids are free. The point is how do you distribute the costs of those goods fairly (i.e. in proportion to use). Utilities are saying netmetering is unfair because it results in stranded costs that must be born by non-solar customers and I am saying that they are overestimating their stranded costs to the extent that they don't count the increase in the efficiency of their ability to serve load (because solar gen is basically already made and delivered electricity they bill for but don't have to buy). It is a really really hard question to know by how much they are overestimating stranded costs.

IMO this is about aggregate demand and the stranded cost thing is a red-herring.


Sources please! There's more to retail than just billing. Off the top of my head there's advertising, acquisition of customers, creation of plans/pricing/campaigns, getting consumption information (which in New Zealand is from 50+ local distribution companies, each with their own formats), there's purchasing from the wholesale market in such a way that you're not losing money all the time, there's setting up a call centre to service those customers, there's meeting regulatory requirements such as a government disputes process, those are just the ones I can think of sitting here.

And I'm not saying that those costs should be massive, I'm just saying those costs exist. Someone must pay for them. Considering I've observed that the margin on retail electricity customers is not much (like $2K of customer lifetime value over 10 years), it's not like in New Zealand electricity companies are rolling around in cash from profit per customer, it's really just a volume game (the company I worked for had 430,000 retail customers).

BTW, the value chain in energy from generation to transmission to meter to cash is full of lots of participants. In New Zealand, the generator, wholesaler, retailer, national distributor, and local distributor are all separate entities. To say "Utilities ... are overestimating their stranded costs to the extent that they don't count the increase in the efficiency of their ability to serve load" ignores the reality of this value chain. At best, this really only benefits the local distributor.


I was coming at it from a US perspective. In the US retail is still dominated by natural monopolies with service areas and captured customers so those costs are low. There is a huge push toward the kind of retail competition you are talking about of course, however, while the growth in the sector is huge the vast majority of customers still behave as captives. https://ei.haas.berkeley.edu/research/papers/WP252.pdf

As for the value chain you are right that I am simplifying but we are on an internet comment board not writing a white paper. However, the simplification doesn't matter. Whether it is vertically integrated utilities or deregulated and unbundled electricity service, the point still stands that stranded costs are overestimated to the extent that they don't account for the fact the netmetered kWhs tend to be high value, are resold at retail, and do not have to be purchased or delivered by the seller. Adding more middleman or more costs just adds accounting wrinkles (and which I think are inappropriate for the forum).

If your point is that the harm is caused by a reduction in aggregate demand then that is a completely different argument.


>Sources please!

Asking for sources for a rebuttal to your opinion is a bit underhanded given that you provided none to backup your claim.

And no, your comment isn't more than an opinion because you've worked in the industry. An informed opinion sure but asking for someone to provide sources to their argument would be a bit hypocritical unless you are going to step up as well.


I enjoy a good internet discussion!

So the topic of debate is whether its fair to charge a retail price for solar buybacks, or a wholesale price. I argued that a retail price is unfair, because energy utilities have a bunch of retail costs, of which billing is one of. The counter argument is that billing is a minute component of the retail cost. You've suggested that I have an informed opinion, but need sources to back up my argument.

Contact Energy have a management paper that discusses energy costs. A definition of Netback from Contact Energy (2015) is:

Netback is calculated by deducting the network, meter, levy and cost to serve costs from customer tariffs. This enables the performance of the retail channels to be measured without using an energy cost. The netback is meant to cover, inter alia, the cost of energy, capital return, risk margin and a retail margin.

Cost of Energy was $994M, while Cost of Transmission and Metering was $621M, and Cost to Serve (such as billing) was $118M for Contact Energy for the year ending 30 June 2015 (Contact Energy, 2015). The remainder, as EBITDAF was $484M.

As you can see, $118M for Cost to Serve is 11.8% of the Cost of Energy. This doesn't change with solar buybacks. The cost of energy is from a different source (your personal solar panels), but there's still costs of transmission and metering, cost to serve, and depending on the utility you connect to, some sort of EBITDAF (unless they're a not for profit). So that's $0 (your solar panels) + $621M (transmission/metering) + $118M (retail/billing) + $484M (earnings before income, tax, depreciation, amortisation, and changes in fair value of financial instruments).

Do check out McNicol (2013) for an interesting article on this.

tl;dr - Electricity networks are expensive, and the cost of energy is about half the total costs of running the system. Who pays for that, if the utility has to pay the retail rate to you because you're using solar panels?

References: Contact Energy. (2015). Management discussion of financial results for the year ended 30 June 2015. Retrieved 9 February 2016 from https://www.contact.co.nz/cenergymedia/contactenergy/files/p...

McNicol, H. (2013). Are solar energy systems worth the cost? Retrieved 9 February 2016 from http://www.stuff.co.nz/the-press/business/the-rebuild/932970...


Here is my point, suppose a kWh costs 10 cents retail. This represents an average cost of maybe 1 cent of profit, 1 cent of admin costs, 3 might be transmission costs, and 5 might be generation costs.

In a 1-1 net metering scheme, I generate 1 kWh in the distribution grid, it goes to my neighbor, the utility bills my neighbor 10, and credits me 1 kWh. When I draw that 1 kWh, the utility loses 2 cents on average. But they also saved 8 cents by selling my kWh to the neighbor. The summing works like this:

10 from my neighbor to the utility 0 from me to the utility -10 for the utility to provide me that kWh 8 to the utility for avoiding the cost of generating and distributing the 1 kWh that went from my system to the neighbor.

The net to the utility is 8 cents. Ouch. But we are talking about the average kWh. It might cost the utility 3 cents to buy an off-peak kWh and 8 cents to buy an on-peak. If that is the case, they are already losing 2 cents for every on-peak kWh they are selling me but making up for it with off-peak (I am likely to use more off-peak anyhow).

In this case, netting might look like the following:

10 from my neighbor to the utility 0 from me to the utility -8 for the utility to provide me an off-peak kWh 11 to the utility for avoiding the cost of generating and distributing the 1 kWh that went from my system to the neighbor.

The net to the utility in this case is 13 cents.

13 cents is better than 8 cents but it is worse than the 20 cents they would have made if I just consumed without generating.

Whether you credit at wholesale or do a .75-1 netmetering or whatever depends on evaluating the stranded costs and whether they are reasonable. Insofar as you look at average kWh prices and not the value of actual production from solar, you inevitably overstate the stranded costs.


Sounds like a case for splitting the delivery cost from the generation cost. Here in Norway I can buy my electricity from an generating company but I also pay the local company for the cost of transmission plus a fixed fee for the connection. This means that the basic infrastructure gets paid for even if I use no electricity at all.


This is true in many states actually. (This model is definitely true in the state I live in)

Nevada specifically seems a bit messed up right now. Politics will have to duke it out... I am not actually on the Solar side of things.


You seem to be missing the fact that utilities charge a "grid connection fee" to cover the cost of overhead like billing. In my case, that fee accounts for half of my bill. You're also failing to consider that solar installations remove load from the grid, allowing utilities to put off upgrades that would have otherwise been inevitable.


> just because midday rates of electricity are high, those high rates tend to subsidise the cost of running the network when rates are low

Prices should be quoted appropriately. Frankly, grid operators should be market makers, continuously quoting bids and asks they'd be happy to buy and sell power at. If the mid-day rate subsidizes the evening, maybe the latter needs to be higher.


They kind of are like this: there are real-time electricity markets in the US. One issue is that a lot of demand is inelastic because price signal transmission is very hard. Grandmas don't want to be adjusting their Air Conditioner on a second-by-second basis due to price fluctuations. Utilities effectively buffer this movement by aggregating demand and purchasing enough to meet that demand.


> Grandmas don't want to be adjusting their Air Conditioner on a second-by-second basis due to price fluctuations. Utilities effectively buffer this movement by aggregating demand and purchasing enough to meet that demand.

This is how Nest makes money. They serve as demand response. You sign up to get a credit on your electric bill, and when demand is extremely high, a utility can signal to Nest to reduce demand for 15 minute increments; its cheaper than firing up a peaking natural gas plant.

https://nest.com/energy-solutions/#demand-response


The high-value kWH logic only holds true with a negligible amount of running solar capacity, however. If we realize the vision of a massive restructuring of energy provision towards photovoltaics, we also have to remodel how to determine the fair price for solar production. In Germany, for example, wholesale rates on sunny days are severely depressed since a few years (which doesn't hurt producers, however, since they were guaranteed fixed feed-in rates, but electricity consumers in general who have to pay for the support programs.)


This is a good point though one thing is that we can pretty much always use more electricity (Alcoa can start smelting more or something) and since we don't have feed-in tariffs I am not sure we will see those same market signals.


Right. In addition, flattening intermittent feed-ins as a business model hasn't really taken up (via large scale storage solutions, for example). Of course FITs strengthen the drive towards market-ignorant feed-ins. Still, as most renewables have very low variable costs, one might expect similar problems in more market-like regimes too.


<Every unit I send back to the grid is a unit that doesn't need to be delivered by the power company but the power company can sell it to my neighbor for retail price.>

Your entire premise assumes that there is an immediate, local, retail consumer who will buy all of your production the instant you produce it. Under the net-metering model, the utility has to pay you retail for the power even if it is surplus and unsellable.


I don't understand your logic for "more valuable" - there's more electricity at midday (because sun) and less usage (because sun and people are at work), so more supply & less demand => price drops, not rises!


Utilities who bill for "time of use" generally have more punitive rates during the day time because of higher demand (and also send these flyers suggesting you use electric washers and dryers closer to midnight).

The fact that people are at work doesn't imply a drop in usage - they just start consuming electricity at the office, retail location, etc.


I suspect that the increased demand such as air conditioning or business-related electrical usage peaks during the daytime (business hours). In hotter climates, air conditioning is a substantial user of electricity, even to the point where some places have to ration their usage of it. Solar puts electricity back on the grid at the time when it's most in demand.


Well in general demand peaks midday while household usage is u-shaped (morning and evening peaks). This makes sense, since when people go to work they are not at home and their work energy use tends to be higher than home energy use. But if you don't like that explanation, simply look at any price curve for any of the organized electricity markets (they are public) and you will see demand and price peaks mid-day.


Aha... so do you have a typo in your answer?

> Solar production peaks midday

should have been

> Solar consumption peaks midday

?


Electricity consumption peaks mid-day, solar or not. Solar production happens to also peak mid-day, which is great because it coincides with the peak consumption period, which makes it more valuable.


No. Solar consumption does peak midday but that is trivial because electricity is nearly always used when it is produced. Electricity demand, which is basically the same thing as consumption, peaks midday (as do prices). And solar production peaks midday. The fact that solar production matches demand is a nice feature of solar that I think militates in favor of net-metering policies.


Ok, I get it... I misread and misunderstood your comment in a few different ways :)


Industrial machinery for facilities that don't run 24 hrs/day increase the draw energy during business hours.


air conditioners in the desert


> The solution here is to raise the fixed portion of the bill to cover the true cost of transmission, and then place a tax on those who go "off grid" to straight out subsidize the poor, so it's more obvious that is what is happening (And presumably most people would still support).

Its going to be untenable to tax someone for no longer using the electric utility (I'm revolted by that idea personally, and am pretty far left bleeding liberal).

You could possibly further subsidize low income electric consumers to have their own system installed using the federal general fund (solar installations receive a 30% tax credit; it might be possible to increase that credit to 50%-75% depending on your adjusted gross income, and have it be a rebate immediately applied at the time of system install).


> Its going to be untenable to tax someone for no longer using the electric utility (I'm revolted by that idea personally, and am pretty far left bleeding liberal).

Which is amusing, because you already pay the tax in the form of variable rate usage pricing that is higher than it needs to be. This is the problem with making hidden subsidies explicit -- people suddenly don't like the subsidy anymore.


If somebody is off-grid and not using the electric utility, they aren't paying any electric bill, so the variable rate is irrelevant?


That's the problem they're trying to fix with this change. As the wealthy, higher consumption customers move off grid, they system as a whole is loosing the subsidies for the poor. Even if you have solar, they power company still have to maintain transmission lines to your house and to the houses of poor people, which was being subsidized by they rich's usage.

So they are trying to stem the tide of the rich leaving by making them continue to bear the cost of subsidizing the poor.

Instead of playing games with those on solar, they should just straight up call it what it is so it is more explicit.


>So they are trying to stem the tide of the rich leaving by making them continue to bear the cost of subsidizing the poor.

No, they're trying to prevent competition. They run power plants too, and they'd rather you bought electricity from them rather than sold it to them.

That's why none of the power companies are advocating just removing the implicit environmental subsidy and allowing power to be sold back to them at wholesale rate.

They just want solar panels gone, period.


How would this work in practice? Let's say I have a piece of land with a shed / cabin / old RV on it that's currently not using electricity, so there's no ongoing relationship with the utility company. If I were to place a solar panel on top of (or a diesel generator, or some kind of car battery hookup), there's a sudden requirement to start sending monthly checks to some entity?


>Its going to be untenable to tax someone for no longer using the electric utility (I'm revolted by that idea personally, and am pretty far left bleeding liberal).

How is that worse than any other tax? You make a choice and the government charges you for making that choice.


The history of net metering comes out of the fact that for many years, smart meters for electricity were very expensive, and not widely deployed. As such, net metering was a natural solution to the billing problem. A user who over-produced for their needs would just run the meter backwards during sunny days, and forwards at night, creating a net metering situation.

It's only with Smart Meters that the utilities can accurately measure per-house production and consumption separately. It's certainly possible to create new billing plans that take advantage of the Smart Meters, but with the capital nature of solar investments, there's a lot of legacy installs to deal with, and those people get angry when they deal they signed up for is changed without grandfathering them into the old way.


Net metering has always been a subsidy for distributed solar. That's what it's intended as.

If you just wanted to account for peak pricing, you could just create a wholesale solar price that estimated average wholesale price for solar in a given area. You could get pretty damn close without having install smart meters.


No, you can just connect two dumb meters. One counts the energy consumption and the other the production.


>Net metering means that the power company is required to buy electricity at retail rates from their customers instead of wholesale rates, which puts quite a burden on them. Why should they have to buy at a higher rate?

It always amuses me when people complain that we're not being "fair" to monopolies.

The whole set up isn't fair. There's no market discipline on the transmission side, so there's no point in transmission being privatized at all.

It's clearly not politically feasible (yet) to push for nationalization but there's no reason to indulge their whinging either.


Oh yeah, low risk business where the government backstops any losses? By rights investors shouldn't expect very high returns.

Also yes with power distribution you have long tail network effects that make charging for service using pure market mechanisms essentially impossible. Hint, when the US stopped subsidizing rail by things like land grants and turning a blind eye to graft, they all went bankrupt.


> Electric companies for decades have been rolling the cost of transmission into the variable rate portion of people's bills.

Perhaps this is the problem, both at ownership and billing level. Why does the utility get to own the power lines instead of the citizens (via local governments and municipalities)? How do you know if utility's claim of the cost of transmission is correct, when they still manage to pay out bonuses to themselves and produce dividends for shareholders? As a consumer you're supposed to blindly trust their statements on costs.


Customers have had to buy electricity from power companies at retail rates rather than wholesale rates since forever. Why should they have to buy at a higher rate?


For a couple of reasons.

- They aren't transmitting it, which has a cost. They aren't providing value add like the power company.

- They could pay wholesale if they figured out a way to get the electricity from the power plant to their house, which is the value add that the power company provides.

- They have a choice in how much they buy, by turning things on and off. The power company, being a regulated utility, does not have that choice. They must buy as much as is demanded.


Obviously because the utility provides the somewhat important role of actually transmitting and distributing the power in question.

Magic faeries don't hand out rights-of-way, substations, 150kv switchyards, transformers, capacitors, conductors, pole provisioning, pylons, transfer switches, and the maintenance of all of the above for free.

Net metering is stealing from those who provide the distribution infrastructure, full stop.


Net metering involves buying and selling kWh. If there are fixed infrastructure costs involved, the companies involved should bill for those separately.

I buy my car from company A and my gasoline from company B with clear prices for A and B.

Why is the scenario where the car company provides my gasoline and then bills for both gasoline and the car in an opaque "single bill" manner, where I can never make out which is which preferable for the consumer?


Net metering is stealing from those who BUY from the providers of the distribution infrastructure, full stop.

Net metering is a subsidy for upper middle class folks who own their houses and want solar panels because it's hip and cool.

The costs get directly passed onto the other consumers. The poor and middle class.


Only in the sense that producing anything as a regulated monopoly is stealing from the consumers of that monopoly good.

People who own solar panels become producers under net-metering. They are just like any other firm in the market. The prices are wonky because they are regulated by law instead of free competition, but the prices of all utilities are wonky because they are regulated by law instead of free competition.


The conventional wisdom is that rooftop solar stresses the grid, and therefore net metering at retail prices amounts to a subsidy extracted from non-solar customers to the benefit of rooftop solar owners.

This, however, is a myth (reinforced at every turn by the incumbent monopolies). Rooftop solar tends to overproduce on the hottest days, which also happens to be the time when the grid is overloaded by air conditioners running at full throttle. In effect, rooftop solar is at maximum production exactly when the grid needs it the most, thus providing very valuable load smoothing. This greatly benefits utilities, since they don’t have to spend as much on peak-generation capacity.

There is ample evidence that utilities underpay for these benefits [1], while their profits rapidly increase. Three major Nevada casino operators “have expressed vocal criticism of NV Energy for generating huge profits over the past years and not lowering rates for customers of Nevada Power. [...] NV Energy’s profits increased 27.7% in 2014, yet the supplier has not introduced any electricity rates breaks to its customers since it was acquired by Berkshire Hathaway.“ [2]

Over the short term, the incumbents will get their way by flexing their political muscle, but this will only delay the inevitable. Electricity spot prices are at their highest during daytime, while people are at work and their solar generators put power into the grid. Utilities want to pay wholesale for this power, then turn around and sell it to non-solar consumers at the top rate. People return from work as their solar generators become inactive, so they will have to buy power at retail rates. For now, utilities will win both ways.

But what this means is that as storage prices drop, it will be more economical to invest in storage capacity in order to capture the valuable power during the day and use it during the night. This will deny utilities the demand-smoothing services that they currently enjoy, so they will have to increase their capex for peak generation, leading to higher rates for everyone else, which in turn will encourage _more_ customers to install solar and storage, etc. Soon after, people will start disconnecting from the grid altogether; welcome to Uber Energy.

Tectonic plates accumulate tension slowly, but they rearrange quickly.

[1] http://cleantechnica.com/2015/09/01/review-of-net-metering-s...

[2] http://www.casinonewsdaily.com/2015/11/26/major-casino-opera...

[reposted from a previous discussion on the topic because the thread had dropped off the front page when the comment was written]


I may be naive, but it would seem more logical to charge consumers solely for the transmission and roll the price of production into that (rather than the other way around). So that the rate you pay per kWh would depend on your proximity to where power is actually being generated on an hourly basis. If you are connected to a substation that is exporting power you would pay less than one that is importing.

If energy costs are so dependant on location and distance why don't we actually acknowledge that in the pricing? If your city is not generating energy why should it pay the same price as one that is?


In the US wholesale energy prices are locational and determined by three things: the cost of energy, congestion in the transmission network, and losses in delivery. Retail rates are also locational but principally determined by state-level organizations (Public Utility Commissions) who regulate the natural monopolies who control the distribution network in the state so they are unable to charge monopoly rents. Rate setting in most places is a very political process.


These are _potential_ problems. They will become real problems when a significant amount of electricity is generated from rooftop solar. That isn't happening yet - according to the article, Nevada has already capped rooftop solar at 3% of peak demand.

Net metering needs to be phased out at some point in the future. Not ended abruptly today.


I think I'm missing something in your position.

Why is the solution to tax people who go off grid?


In Germany, wholesale power prices can actually go negative on sunny afternoons. Conditions in the US are trending towards that.

Why should actual generators get paid low (or negative) wholesale prices at the exact same moment that some consumer gets paid full retail rates? It doesn't make sense.

Very practically, this is illustrated by California's duck curve. Also from Bloomberg:

http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-10-21/california...

It has nothing to do with Musk and Buffet. How do you price power, both wholesale and retail, in a way that recognizes that there's a need to provide power even when it has been overcast for three weeks? It's crazy to unfairly penalize power companies just because the public loves solar power.

It's a complicated question.


You are talking about spot market prices, not wholesale power prices. Most of the wholesale prices are established in forward markets (several months to a day ahead) and I don't remember ever seeing them negative. So following your logic it would be unfair that some power plants can run and earn positive income (when their production is sold forward) at the same time when other need to pay to run (when their production is sold on spot market). But there is nothing wrong in this - that's how balancing in power markets works.

Also you mentioned that wholesale and retail power prices can be very different. There are multiple of reasons why this is the case, but the important result is that consumers do not understand how balancing market works and why prices can be one hour $1000 and the next negative. If we want to encourage solar power installations by retail customers the pricing should also be based on retail model.

So I would disagree that your comment about negative prices is relevant to how prices should be set for power produced by home solar panels.

But I do agree - it is quite complicated question as most questions concerning power grid.



It's a little weird that the article claims that the problem is worst in winter, when there is least sun.

Also, that graph is unreadable? I'm already aware of what the duck curve is, and I can't make head nor tail of it.


I bet it's a problem in the winter due to A/C and electric heating. When it's sunny in summer, solar production goes up but it also makes people use A/C more. There is significant canceling out.

In winter, solar production goes up, but people use less energy due to electric heaters not be as needed since it's warmer. Not a lot of the country uses electric heaters, but it's enough to add to the problem.


This whole article is weird to me as a New Zealander, since most of the problems comes from weirdly, not letting the market set the buy-back rate of electricity.

I worked for one of New Zealand's largest electricity generators and retailers, and we investigated a solar market. Here's how it works.

Electricity is broken up into generation costs, distribution costs, retail costs, regulatory costs, and profit.

Generation capacity goes up and down throughout the day, as does demand. In New Zealand an automated auction happens 30 minutes where generators bid in electricity at a price. The system operator then buys capacity required at any particular area at the cheapest price that is available. This sets the wholesale price of electricity.

This then gets distributed by the system operator throughout the country to a local lines company. They maintain the power lines to your house, but also to that person in the middle of nowhere.

The energy company figures out how much you've consumed, and bills you. Of course, when you have a problem, you call them, so there's a call centre always available as well.

Finally, there are taxes and levies that the government applies.

After all that, if there's anything left over between the retail price, and the sum of those costs, well, that's the profit.

The weird bit is, where do you set the buyback rate for solar? The retail price? But there's so much expenses there, not all of which are the retailer's cost. The fair price of the market is the generating price, or wholesale price. But, there maybe political incentives to set a higher rate, as well as cap the number of people who can get that higher rate.

But if you want it sustainable for everybody, then using the wholesale rate makes more sense.


What you just said is that the buyback rate should be somewhere between wholesale rate and retail. There is no clear cut way to figure out what it should be so regulators and politicians get involved in setting the rate.

"Sustainable for everybody" argument can be used on both sides - if rate is set too low, the solar panel owners subsidize the rest of the customers if it is set too high then other customers subsidize solar panel owners.

So the argument is not as clear as you tried to make it sound.


There is a clear cut way - the wholesale rate. In New Zealand, an auction happens every 30 minutes where demand is tallied by the system operator (Transpower) at a Grid Extraction Point, and generators bid in what they think it's worth.

The system operator then purchases the cheapest electricity available (taking into account demand is different throughout the network, and the network can't transfer all electricity to all parts of the grid because of line constraints).

This is the cost of the 'raw materials' of the retail electricity price. A solar panel on your house really isn't any different that a little power station. You still have to transport that electricity somewhere, maintain those lines, maintain the voltage, run a power station when it gets dark, bill you, etc.

It's not a big conspiracy, it's just that the cost of energy makes up about half the costs of the electricity system. If you set at a rate higher than the wholesale rate, then there must be other reasons to do so rather than pure financials.

A good example would be if an Energy Utility wanted to attract solar customers, sell them solar systems, and put it on the bill to make them more sticky customers.


That's not quite what the wholesale rate means in the US; we have what you describe but it's typically referred to as the spot market. The wholesale rate when used by politicians and the media here usually (as far as I know) refers to the monthly auction clearing rate, which is much more stable. There is also a day-ahead wholesale rate, but the net metering rollback bills I've read recently are all based on the monthly auction rate.


Haven't finished the article yet, but that animated gif of Warren vs Elon is... something special.



Or don't unless you want this image for ever burned into your retinas....


I wonder how they decide which article have such animation. Is it the journalists that ask for an animation or a graphic designer that looks at all articles and propose to add animations to some of them ?


Gosh, I'm surprised and impressed at how non-traditional Bloomberg's digital content is. I've never seen a big name increasingly take these kinds of liberties on a continuing basis.


The long term question here is will solar be distributed or centralized? I think the answer is distributed like the model Elon and solar city are using. It just doesn't makes sense for the old power companies like Buffet's NV Energy to maintain all the transmission lines when the cost of batteries falls.


Couldn't one argue exactly the opposite? Since, due to physics, electricity is very hard to store and there are already transmission lines, why not use them?

There are going to be factories that probably can't realistically be supported by batteries. Another alternative is to run only in the summer and on sunny days. Or to do all heavy industry/manufacturing close to hydro, nuclear or geothermal power sources. In a sense, it would be a return towards the old mill brook economy.

They recently opened a big subsea transmission cable between Netherlands and Norway. Norway has mountains for hydro load balancing while Netherlands has wind turbines for volatile production.


In Australia the grid in already encouraging some outlying towns to leave the grid as just maintaining existing grid connections over long distances is more expensive that creating a micro-grid for them.


The factory nearby here (a paper mill) has a larger power plant than the ~35,000 people that live in the area.

They aren't going to switch to something less reliable than the natural gas line feeding the plant, nor are they going to switch to something more expensive.

It typically only shuts down for several weeks a year and isn't all that profitable (at least, the owners keep going bankrupt, 4 or 5 times in the recent 20 years), I doubt running less would help.


Paper has become a worse and worse business since electronic media has taken over gradually.

But the "turn factories off" was a bit of a joke. Though Nordpool does have its spikes and it indeed makes sense to sometimes turn off factories. Depends on your process.

Nowadays they run data centers in some old paper factories here (since the electricity is cheap). So in a sense the old industries are gone, from lack of demand, and new industries have gone where there is cheap power available.


The thought was that industry doesn't necessarily care about the grid, it just treats it as an option and calculates whether it is a good one.

(hence pointing out that it was the largest energy consumer in the area and had already opted out of buying grid power, that it's not in a great industry strengthens the point)


> Since, due to physics, electricity is very hard to store and there are already transmission lines,

You're going to have to actually argue "due to physics" on this one, it's far more like "due to technology and engineering.

Transmission lines are hugely expensive, involve stringing valuable materials for miles. The cost is going to vary widely throughout the grid, but the EIA estimates an average of ~$0.04/kWh across the entire US [1].

Most storage costs are somewhat easier to estimate, as batteries costs are well known. Current prices on new lithium ion batteries put the cost at ~$0.15-$0.20/kWh. This is probably not the most cost effective storage model, vanadium redox flow batteries, or hydro storage, or used car lithium ion batteries will drive this down substantially. Also, storage costs are dropping dramatically, while transmission costs are unlikely to change much.

For many locations, it may make far more sense to pay $0.20/kWh than to build out the grid to that location. And this is definitely true for many locations, even in California, that are only a few miles away from grid-connected homes. It's all a matter of the costs of current technology, discount rates for the cost of up-front capital investments, and the expected tech curve.

Long-distance transmission does have the potential to hugely improve the cost-effectiveness of intermittent renewables. A recent study tried to optimize costs using high-voltage DC interties between US grids to distribute renewable energy across the country, and found that storage was not necessary, even when transitioning a huge percentage of the power source to renewables. [2]

>There are going to be factories that probably can't realistically be supported by batteries

This again is all a matter of cost. I do think that transmission can help a ton here. But I think there's going to be both time shifting (storage) and distance shifting (transmission) in the future.

I think that people underestimate the rate at which storage will get cheap, just as they did with wind and solar, but that's just my humble opinion.

[1] http://www.eia.gov/forecasts/aeo/pdf/tbla8.pdf

[2] http://arstechnica.com/science/2016/01/making-a-single-us-el...


Well, I think it really depends on the economics of grid storage and proximity.

For instance, there was someone saying they pay $.10/kwh year round on a thread the other day and it was due to their proximity to grid storage.

$.10 to .15/kwh is realistically the range battery technology will be in for the next 10-15 years, barring a major technological change. That simply is not going to be cost effective in many areas.

EDIT:

Since I can't post...

http://www.computerworld.com/article/2977655/sustainable-it/...

> As energy push accelerates, battery costs set to plunge 60%

> Lithium-ion (Li-on) batteries will drop from $550 per kilowatt hour (kWh) in 2014 to $200 per kWh by 2020; and flow battery prices will drop from $680 per kWh to $350 per kWh during the same time.

A daily cycle, 5 year battery is still going to be ~$.11/kwh in 2020.

You need generation + battery storage [combined] to get into the below $.15/kwh for it to make sense outside of peak June-Sept, 2-7pm times.


> $.10 to .15/kwh is realistically the range battery technology will be in for the next 10-15 years

Forgive the lack of citation, but Goldman Sachs just put out a report on Tesla within the last few days, and they're estimating the cost of batteries dropping ~60% over 5 years due to the Gigafactory producing 35GW of storage each year.

EDIT: Found it, http://evannex.com/blogs/news/75718469-goldman-sachs-bullish...

"Discussing electric vehicle batteries, Goldman reports that: "technological advances play a significant role, growing economies of scale are the key driver of cost reductions. Led by Tesla and Panasonic’s 35GW Gigafactory, battery manufacturers have committed to approximately triple current production capacity over the next five years [Exhibit 36].... Autos analysts forecast the battery range for lower performance EVs to increase by over 70%, while battery costs are expected to fall by more than 60% over the next five years [Exhibit 37].""


Solid pricing information for large quantities of batteries is hard to get, but GM recently disclosed their price to be $145/kWh, and apparently LG Chem's other customers are paying around ~$100 more/kWh [1].

Is your $0.11/kWh price just for the stored amount at $200/kWh? That conversion factor to kWh-stored prices is more favorable than I've been using, as I've been assuming about ~1000 cycles worth of storage, but then I don't really have a good number for that.

Since not all energy will need to be stored, and much (most?) can be used right away, then it will increase the overall cost of energy only by the X% that needs to be stored. So if solar is $0.05/kWh, and 50% can be used right away, then the overall cost for solar + storage would be $0.105/kWh on the generation side. Which is quite competitive already.

http://insideevs.com/lg-chem-ticked-gm-disclosing-145kwh-bat...


> Is your $0.11/kWh price just for the stored amount at $200/kWh? That conversion factor to kWh-stored prices is more favorable than I've been using, as I've been assuming about ~1000 cycles worth of storage, but then I don't really have a good number for that.

Yeah. I don't really have good numbers but Powerwalls have a 10 year guarantee iirc and many batteries have a 5 year guarantee so I was using a higher number.

> Solid pricing information for large quantities of batteries is hard to get, but GM recently disclosed their price to be $145/kWh, and apparently LG Chem's other customers are paying around ~$100 more/kWh [1].

GM isn't selling it to consumers at $200/kwh but is buying them from LG Chem and its a deal for far larger production runs. GM is going to get a much better deal than you or I [who will only buy a single bank of batteries every 5 years].


I just read that the Tesla Powerwall has a warranty to 5,000 cycles [1], which is 5x what I thought it would be. Without installation costs, that's $0.095/kWh == $3000 / (7kWh * 5000 cycles * 0.9 efficiency).

Which means that consumer storage is already within your $0.11/kWh price; that's completely astounding to me, and means that on the grid scale it will be even cheaper.... I imagine that the days of peaker plants are coming to a close entirely.

This conversation has made me hugely optimistic. Huge swathes of the country are already primed to go completely off grid, economically, then. If solar costs $0.06/kWh, and half of the energy is stored at $0.10/kWh, that's a total price of $0.11/kWh for an off-grid site. That's far cheaper than what I pay for electricity right now.

https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Tesla_Powerwall#cite_note-2015...


I think there will be both. In dense areas there is more electricity demand than available space for panels. There are also lots of very sunny areas without any people in the way.


Distributed to what level - block, township, city, county, state? SCTY and others are already experimenting with "community storage" http://www.greentechmedia.com/articles/read/Lesson-Learned-F...


Long term, it will be distributed but Utilities are fighting their fight. They want to collect rent on transmission lines, so we are not too far away where Solar customers would have accept that they have to pay say $50 fee for connecting to grid etc. That may help the utilities medium term, but if wall-mounts become economical, we may truly see off-grid take off.


There would need to be a massive oversupply of energy to make a distributed model work since you can't share the excess you have or get extra when you need it.

I don't think people would be happy moving to a battery-only model where if their power usage spiked they were SOL until they installed more solar.

And that's assuming everyone has the space to install enough solar; residential high rises certainly wouldn't be able to power themselves unless they coated their sides with solar panels, and that may not even work in dense neighborhoods.

Unless the whole solar + battery kit was significantly cheaper than grid solar, not just on a per watt basis, but with all the overcapacity you need for fluctuations to not be brutal, I doubt the predominant model will be distributed.


The panels themself will be decentralized but I believe that every business will be centralized once it's profitable in itself and in widespread use. E.g. the gas in the car is yours, but the gas station is a global huge giant that has more control over gas than you.


As you seem imply, the trade-off here is between the costs of distribution and economies of scale. However, without numbers for the various costs, I don't see how you can make a prediction.


Isn't solar power more efficient when concentrated? That should favor centralized solutions, shouldn't it?


What type of efficiency are you talking about? For kWh/$ efficiency, non-concentrated flat-panel solar is the most efficient.

Concentrated solar power in practice is usually thermally based, heating up something and then generating electricity from that. It's more expensive, but also is a form of storage, so depending on the use case it may be cheaper over all, but that's highly dependent on the situation.


> All this has enraged independent, free-market, and environmentally conscious Nevadans.

I'm all for green energy, but how is leasing solar panels that are government subsidized and then having companies forced to buy back electricity at a set price considered part of a "free market"?


They might be more upset about being forced to pay to not be connected to the grid. It's not free market if a customer can't refuse to be connected to the grid and refuse to pay for it.


It's not. The energy production market is nowhere near a free market, thus these pricing absurdities for net metering.


"All this has enraged independent, free-market, and environmentally conscious Nevadans."

...

"Nevada forces utilities to buy the excess energy at rates set by regulators"

How was the government forcing utilities to buy excess energy at mandated rates "free market"?


Plus there is the fact that utilities are state-regulated monopolies... Until you have competing utility providers, it isn't much of a market.


We changed the title so it wouldn't be ludicrous linkbait. If anyone can suggest a better (more accurate and neutral) title, we're happy to change it again.

Submitters: the HN guidelines ask you not to use the original title when it is linkbait or misleading. Please change it in such cases, preferably using a subtitle or representative phrase from the article. (I couldn't find one in this case, but if anyone else does, let us know.)


Here's the problem with Net Metering: suppose you have two neighbors with exactly the same sunlight conditions:

1. A person whose house is large, inefficient, and uses a lot of electricity

2. A person with a small efficient house.

If both of these people buy the exact same solar panels and generate the exact same amount of electricity, then the utility has to pay #1 a lot more money than #2. (If you really want to ramp up the rhetoric, call #1 rich and #2 poor, and ask why the rich guy gets paid more for his solar power)

How does this happen? In order to encourage conservation, we have different price tiers. The more electricity you use the higher the price per usage is. When the solar "rolls the meter backwards", it's rolling away the high-cost tier from the wasteful guy, and the low-cost tier from the conservationist.

We want to encourage solar generation, so it makes sense that solar generators should be paid more per kWh. Net Metering is the Wrong Way to accomplish this goal.


Meta comment : it's always surprising to see how different is the destiny of a submission based on timing and randomness. For example, my previous submission of this link got only one vote. (https://news.ycombinator.com/item?id=11052575)


On a second thought, the utilities should have never been privatised.


It reminds me of A Connecticut Yankee in King Arthurs Court after the Interdict came down and stopped all that progress. Our Interdict is the PUC, regulation, lobbyists and corrupt political decisions, then subsidies and more counter subsidies. No, rooftop solar is not a no brainer anywhere. Try to figure in the cost of energy storage which is still astronomical in price. Or jump into 100 years of utility regulation fights when all we need is power generation that should be just based on common law rights etc and competitive capitalism only.


"For years the state provided rebates for homeowners who wanted to go solar through a lottery system."

What the heck...




Guidelines | FAQ | Lists | API | Security | Legal | Apply to YC | Contact

Search: